Jump to content

Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act: Difference between revisions

From Wikipedia, the free encyclopedia
Content deleted Content added
Fixed profanity, removed "PENIS"
→‎Bibliography: Koyama, Kumiko, “The Passage of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act: Why Did the President Sign the Bill?,” Journal of Policy History, 21 (no. 2, 2009), 163–86.
Line 86: Line 86:
*{{cite book |title=American Trade Policy: 1923–1995 |last=Kaplan |first=Edward S. |authorlink= |coauthors= |year=1996 |publisher=Greenwood Press |location=London |isbn=0313294801 |pages= }}
*{{cite book |title=American Trade Policy: 1923–1995 |last=Kaplan |first=Edward S. |authorlink= |coauthors= |year=1996 |publisher=Greenwood Press |location=London |isbn=0313294801 |pages= }}
* Kottman, Richard N. "Herbert Hoover and the Smoot-Hawley Tariff: Canada, A Case Study," ''Journal of American History'', Vol. 62, No. 3 (Dec., 1975), pp. 609-635 [http://www.jstor.org/stable/2936217 in JSTOR]
* Kottman, Richard N. "Herbert Hoover and the Smoot-Hawley Tariff: Canada, A Case Study," ''Journal of American History'', Vol. 62, No. 3 (Dec., 1975), pp. 609-635 [http://www.jstor.org/stable/2936217 in JSTOR]
* Koyama, Kumiko, “The Passage of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act: Why Did the President Sign the Bill?,” ''Journal of Policy History,'' 21 (no. 2, 2009), 163–86.
*{{cite journal |last=Madsen |first=Jakob B. |authorlink= |coauthors= |year=2001 |month= |title=Trade Barriers and the Collapse of World Trade during the Great Depression |journal=Southern Economic Journal |volume=67 |issue=4 |pages=848–868 |doi=10.2307/1061574 |url= |accessdate= |quote= }}
*{{cite journal |last=Madsen |first=Jakob B. |authorlink= |coauthors= |year=2001 |month= |title=Trade Barriers and the Collapse of World Trade during the Great Depression |journal=Southern Economic Journal |volume=67 |issue=4 |pages=848–868 |doi=10.2307/1061574 |url= |accessdate= |quote= }}
*{{cite journal |last=McDonald |first=Judith |authorlink= |coauthors=O'Brien, Anthony Patrick; Callahan, Colleen |year=1997 |month= |title=Trade Wars: Canada's Reaction to the Smoot-Hawley Tariff |journal=Journal of Economic History |volume=57 |issue=4 |pages=802–826 |doi=10.2307/2951161 |url= |accessdate= |quote= }}
*{{cite journal |last=McDonald |first=Judith |authorlink= |coauthors=O'Brien, Anthony Patrick; Callahan, Colleen |year=1997 |month= |title=Trade Wars: Canada's Reaction to the Smoot-Hawley Tariff |journal=Journal of Economic History |volume=57 |issue=4 |pages=802–826 |doi=10.2307/2951161 |url= |accessdate= |quote= }}

Revision as of 12:10, 15 April 2010

Willis C. Hawley (left) and Reed Smoot in April 1929, shortly before the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act passed the House of Representatives.

The Smoot-Hawley Tariff (P.L. 71-361, sometimes known under its official name, the Tariff Act of 1930)[1] was an act signed into law on June 17, 1930, that raised U.S. tariffs on over 20,000 imported goods to record levels. The overall level tariffs under the Tariff were the second-highest in US history, exceeded only (by a small margin) by the Tariff of 1828.[2] The ensuing retaliatory tariffs by U.S. trading partners reduced American exports and imports by more than half and contributed to the severity of the Great Depression.[3][4][5]

Ensuing laws have virtually eliminated the Act’s most onerous provisions, yet it remains as permanent authority and a vehicle for trade legislation.

Causes

Although rated capacity of the U.S. manufacturing sector had increased tremendously in the post-World War I period, actual output, income, and expenditure had not. Under the direction of Republican Senator Reed Smoot of Utah, the party had drafted the Fordney-McCumber tariff act in 1922 which increased tariffs with the purpose of increasing domestic firms' market share. Weakening labor markets in 1927 and 1928 prompted Smoot to propose yet another tariff increase (Smoot-Hawley Tariff Bill).

In his memoirs, Smoot made it abundantly clear:

"The world is paying for its ruthless destruction of life and property in the World War and for its failure to adjust purchasing power to productive capacity during the industrial revolution of the decade following the war."[6]

Sponsors and legislative history

The act was originated by Senator Reed Smoot, a Republican from Utah, and Representative Willis C. Hawley, a Republican from Oregon.

When campaigning for president during 1928, one of Herbert Hoover's many campaign promises to help beleaguered farmers had been to increase tariffs of agricultural products. Hoover won, and Republicans maintained comfortable majorities in the House and the Senate during 1928. Hoover then asked Congress for an increase of tariff rates for agricultural goods and a decrease of rates for industrial goods.

The House passed a version of the act in May 1929, increasing tariffs on agricultural and industrial goods alike. The Senate debated its bill until March 1930, with many Senators trading votes based on their states' industries. The conference committee then aligned the two versions, largely by moving to the greater House tariffs.[7]

Opponents

In May 1930, a petition was signed by 1028 economists in the United States asking President Herbert Hoover to veto the legislation, organized by Paul Douglas, Irving Fisher, James TFG Wood, Frank Graham, Ernest Patterson, Henry Seager, Frank Taussig, and Clair Wilcox.[8][9] Automobile executive Henry Ford spent an evening at the White House trying to convince Hoover to veto the bill, calling it "an economic stupidity".[10] J. P. Morgan's chief executive Thomas W. Lamont said he "almost went down on my knees to beg Herbert Hoover to veto the asinine Hawley-Smoot tariff."[11]

Hoover opposed the bill and called it "vicious, extortionate, and obnoxious" because he felt it would undermine the commitment he had pledged to international cooperation. Later events would reveal Hoover was right: the international community levied their own tariffs in retaliation after the bill had become law. However, in spite of his opposition, Hoover yielded to influence from his own party and business leaders and signed the bill.[12]

Franklin D. Roosevelt spoke against the act while campaigning for president during 1932.[7]

Retaliation

Retaliation began long before the bill was enacted into law in June 1930. As it passed the House of Representatives in May 1929, boycotts broke out and foreign governments moved to increase rates against American products, even though rates could be increased or decreased by the Senate or by the conference committee. By September 1929, Hoover's administration had received protest notes from 23 trading partners, but threats of retaliatory actions were ignored.[7]

In May 1930, the greatest trading partner Canada preemptively imposed new tariffs on 16 products that accounted altogether for around 30% of U.S. exports to Canada.[13] Canada later also forged closer economic links with the British Commonwealth. France and Britain protested and developed new trade partners. Germany developed a system of autarky.

Both Reed Smoot and Willis Hawley were defeated for reelection in 1932, the controversial tariff being a major factor in their respective losses.

Economic effects

At first the tariff seemed to be a success. According to historian Robert Sobel, "Factory payrolls, construction contracts, and industrial production all increased sharply." However, larger economic problems loomed in the guise of weak banks. When the Kredit-Anstalt Bank of Austria failed, the global deficiencies of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff became apparent.[12]

U.S. imports decreased 66% from US$4.4 billion (1929) to US$1.5 billion (1933), and exports decreased 61% from US$5.4 billion to US$2.1 billion, both decreases much more than the 50% decrease of the GDP.

According to government statistics, U.S. imports from Europe decreased from a 1929 high of $1,334 million to just $390 million during 1932, while U.S. exports to Europe decreased from $2,341 million in 1929 to $784 million in 1932. Overall, world trade decreased by some 66% between 1929 and 1934.[14]

There is not any universal agreement about the effect of the tariff. According to the U.S. Statistical Abstract, the effective tariff rate was 13.5% in 1929 and 19.8% in 1933 with 63% of all imports being duty-free. From 1821 through 1900 the United States averaged 29.7% effective tariff rates and peaked in 1830 at 57.3% with only 8% of all imports being duty-free, dwarfing the Smoot-Hawley rate. In addition, imports during 1929 were only 4.2% of the United States' GNP and exports were only 5.0%. For monetarist authors who consider the Great Depression an effect of the monetary policy of the Federal Reserve, the Smoot-Hawley's effect on the entire U.S. economy may have been small compared to monetary policy. By 1937 the effective tariff rate was reduced to 15.6% when the reaction of 1937–1938 occurred, demonstrating no statistical correlation between this economic downturn and tariff levels. Senator Robert L. Owen testified at the hearings on HR 7230, the bill to make the Federal Reserve banks a national property, that "In 1937, when the Federal Reserve Board called upon the banks to raise their reserves to twice what they had been before, there was a contraction of credit of two billion dollars.[15]

Using panel data estimates of export and import equations for 17 countries, Jakob B. Madsen (2002) estimated the effects of increasing tariff and non-tariff trade barriers on worldwide trade during the period 1929–1932. He concluded that real international trade contracted somewhere around 33% overall. His estimates of the impact of various factors included about 14% because of declining GNP in each country, 8% because of increases in tariff rates, 5% because of deflation-induced tariff increases, and 6% because of the imposition of nontariff barriers.

The Smoot–Hawley Tariff Act "imposed an effective tax rate of 60% on more than 3,200 products and materials imported into the United States", quadrupling previous tariff rates.

Although the tariff act was passed after the stock-market crash of 1929, some economic historians consider the political discussion leading up to the passing of the act a factor in causing the crash, the recession that began in late 1929, or both, and its eventual passage a factor in deepening the Great Depression.[16] Unemployment was at 7.8% in 1930 when the Smoot-Hawley tariff was passed, but it jumped to 16.3% in 1931, 24.9% in 1932, and 25.1% in 1933.[17]

End of the tariffs

As a result of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff and other countries' responses to it, the world after World War II saw a push towards multi-lateral trading agreements that would prevent a similar situation from unfolding. This led to the Bretton Woods Agreement, in 1944, a great lessening of global tariffs starting in December 1945, and the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade, in the 1950s.[18]

However, the American Tariff League Study of 1951 which compared the effective tariff levels of 43 countries found that only seven countries had a lower tariff level than the United States (5.1%). Eleven countries had effective tariff rates higher than the Smoot-Hawley peak of 19.8% including the United Kingdom (25.6%). The 43-country average was 14.4% ± 0.9% higher than the U.S. level of 1929.

In addition to tariffs, many countries implemented non-tariff barriers to protect their industries in the aftermath of World War II after experiencing the dangers of dependence on imports for vital supplies brought upon by free-trade policies. Many nations felt the ill effects of embargoes, naval blockades and submarine warfare upon their national security. An example of this involved Britain and France importing all of their watches and clocks from Switzerland and Germany prior to World War II. They discovered that the lack of a watch industry was a great handicap in building defense equipment during the war. Both nations determined never to be without a watch industry again and placed embargoes on watch imports after World War II.[19]

Non-tariff barriers would become more important in the post-WW II reconstruction period. Japan for example, with an effective tariff rate of 1.6% in 1951 would put many non-tariff barriers in place. In June 1952 Japan's "Basic Policy for the Introduction of Foreign Investment into Japan's Passenger Car Industry" placed quotas, tariffs and commodity taxes on imports that closed the Japanese automobile market to American manufacturers for nearly two decades.[20] Japan would also make extensive use of licensing agreements which would transfer foreign technology to Japan in exchange for limited market access as in the case of the U.S. television industry. With Japan's home market protected, Japanese manufacturers could make large profits at home to offset the cost of selling their goods at reduced prices in foreign markets (dumping).

Presence in modern political dialogue

In the discussion leading up to the passage of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) then Vice-President Al Gore mentioned the tariff as a response to NAFTA objections voiced by Ross Perot during a debate in 1993 they had on the Larry King Show. He gave Perot a framed picture of Smoot and Hawley shaking hands after its passage.[7]

The tariff was revisited during the 2008 presidential election and during the recession of the late 2000s by some politicians to caution against adopting protectionist policies.

The 1986 comedy film Ferris Bueller's Day Off includes a scene where former Richard Nixon speech writer Ben Stein, in the role of a high school teacher, leads a class discussion about the "Hawley-Smoot" Tariff Act.[21]

The Hawley-Smoot Tariff appears repeatedly in Dave Barry's Dave Barry Slept Here: A Sort of History of the United States because, "We think it has a wonderful ring to it, and we just like to see it in large bold letters."[22]

See also

References

  1. ^ ch. 497, 46 Stat. 590, June 17, 1930, see 19 U.S.C. § 1654
  2. ^ WWS 543: Class notes, 2/17/10, Paul Krugman, February 16, 2010, Presentation, slide 4
  3. ^ Hawley-Smoot Tariff, U.S. Department of State.
  4. ^ http://www.state.gov/r/pa/ho/time/id/17606.htm
  5. ^ See Causes of the Great Depression: Protectionism for further discussion of the role of protectionism in the Great Depression.
  6. ^ Merill, Milton 1990, Reed Smoot: Apostle in Politics, Logan UT: Utah State Press. p. 340.
  7. ^ a b c d "The Battle of Smoot-Hawley", The Economist, 18 December 2008
  8. ^ The New York Times, May 5, 1930). Special to The New York Times"1,028 Economists Ask Hoover To Veto Pending Tariff Bill": Professors in 179 Colleges and Other Leaders Assail Rise in Rates as Harmful to Country and Sure to Bring Reprisals.
  9. ^ "Economists Against Smoot-Hawley" (Sep 2007). Econ Journal Watch
  10. ^ "Shades of Smoot-Hawley", Time magazine, October 7, 1985.
  11. ^ Ron Chernow, House of Morgan, p.323, 1990
  12. ^ a b Sobel, Robert. The Age of Giant Corporations, p 87–88.
  13. ^ Wilson B. Brown and Jan S. Hogendorn. International Economics: In the Age of Globalization. Retrieved from http://www.google.com.au/books?id=5SoP6KUDwY4C&pg=PA246&dq=smoot+hawley&sig=GplUGJBCti3Tv3XN2saPicP5Lsw
  14. ^ http://future.state.gov/when/timeline/1921_timeline/smoot_tariff.html
  15. ^ Eustace Mullins, The Federal Reserve Conspiracy, 1971, p.122
  16. ^ How the Republicans Caused the Stock Market Crash of 1929 by Bernard Beaudreau: [1]
  17. ^ Source: U.S. Bureau of the Census, Historical Statistics of the United States, Colonial Times to 1957 (Washington, D.C., 1960), p.70.
  18. ^ "Understanding the WTO: The GATT years: from Havana to Marrakesh", wto.org
  19. ^ Lewis E. Lloyd, Tariffs: The Case For Protection, 1955, p. 137–139
  20. ^ Eugene J. Kaplan, Japan: The Government-Business Relationship, Bureau of International Commerce, February 1972, p.111–112
  21. ^ Internet Movie Database: Ferris Bueller's Day Off (1986) - Memorable Quotes
  22. ^ Barry, Dave. Dave Barry Slept Here: A Sort of History of the United States. New York: Ballantine Books, 1989: The United States has experienced short periods of depression, but the Great depression of the 1930's was a 10-year long nightmare. 152.

Bibliography

  • Archibald, Robert B. (1998). "Investment During the Great Depression: Uncertainty and the Role of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff". Southern Economic Journal. 64 (4): 857–879. doi:10.2307/1061208. {{cite journal}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |month= (help); Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)
  • Beaudreau, Bernard C. (2005). Making Sense of Smoot-Hawley: Tariffs and Technology. New York: iUniverse. {{cite book}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |coauthors= (help)
  • Buchanan, Patrick J. (1998). The Great Betrayal: How American Sovereignty and Social Justice Are Being Sacrificed to the Gods of the Global Economy. Boston: Little ↦ Brown. ISBN 0316115185. {{cite book}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |coauthors= (help)
  • Crucini, Mario J. (1994). "Sources of variation in real tariff rates: The United States 1900 to 1940". American Economic Review. 84 (3): 346–353. doi:10.2307/2118081. {{cite journal}}: Cite has empty unknown parameters: |month= and |coauthors= (help); Unknown parameter |doi_brokendate= ignored (|doi-broken-date= suggested) (help)
  • Crucini, Mario J. (1996). "Tariffs and Aggregate Economic Activity: Lessons from the Great Depression". Journal of Monetary Economics. 38 (3): 427–467. doi:10.1016/S0304-3932(96)01298-6. {{cite journal}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |month= (help); Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)
  • Eckes, Alfred (1995). Opening America's Market: U.S. Foreign Trade Policy since 1776. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press. ISBN 0585029059. {{cite book}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |coauthors= (help)
  • Eichengreen, Barry (1989). "The Political Economy of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff". Research in Economic History. 12: 1–43. {{cite journal}}: Cite has empty unknown parameters: |month= and |coauthors= (help)
  • Irwin, Douglas (1998). "The Smoot-Hawley Tariff: A Quantitative Assessment". Review of Economics and Statistics. 80 (2): 326–334. doi:10.1162/003465398557410. {{cite journal}}: Cite has empty unknown parameters: |month= and |coauthors= (help)
  • Kaplan, Edward S. (1996). American Trade Policy: 1923–1995. London: Greenwood Press. ISBN 0313294801. {{cite book}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |coauthors= (help)
  • Kottman, Richard N. "Herbert Hoover and the Smoot-Hawley Tariff: Canada, A Case Study," Journal of American History, Vol. 62, No. 3 (Dec., 1975), pp. 609-635 in JSTOR
  • Koyama, Kumiko, “The Passage of the Smoot-Hawley Tariff Act: Why Did the President Sign the Bill?,” Journal of Policy History, 21 (no. 2, 2009), 163–86.
  • Madsen, Jakob B. (2001). "Trade Barriers and the Collapse of World Trade during the Great Depression". Southern Economic Journal. 67 (4): 848–868. doi:10.2307/1061574. {{cite journal}}: Cite has empty unknown parameters: |month= and |coauthors= (help)
  • McDonald, Judith (1997). "Trade Wars: Canada's Reaction to the Smoot-Hawley Tariff". Journal of Economic History. 57 (4): 802–826. doi:10.2307/2951161. {{cite journal}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |month= (help); Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)
  • Merill, Milton (1990). Reed Smoot: Apostle in Politics. Logan, UT: Utah State Press. ISBN 0874211271. {{cite book}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |coauthors= (help)
  • O'Brien, Anthony. "Smoot-Hawley Tariff". EH Encyclopedia.
  • Pastor, Robert (1980). Congress and the Politics of U.S. Foreign Economic Policy, 1929–1976. Berkeley: University of California Press. ISBN 0520039041. {{cite book}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |coauthors= (help)
  • Schattschneider, E. E. (1935). Politics, Pressures and the Tariff. New York: Prentice-Hall. {{cite book}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |coauthors= (help) → Classic study of passage of Hawley-Smoot tariff
  • Taussig, F. W. (1931). The Tariff History of the United States (PDF) (8th ed.). New York: G.P. Putnam's Sons. {{cite book}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |coauthors= (help)
  • Temin, Peter (1989). Lessons from the Great Depression. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. ISBN 0262200732. {{cite book}}: Cite has empty unknown parameter: |coauthors= (help)
  • Turney, Elaine C. Prange (2003). Tariffs and Trade in U.S. History: An Encyclopedia. {{cite book}}: Unknown parameter |coauthors= ignored (|author= suggested) (help)